New Ideas for a Do-Something Congress No. 2: Jumpstart a New Generation of Manufacturing Entrepreneurs

The number of large U.S. manufacturing facilities has dropped by more than a third since 2000, devastating many communities where factories were the lifeblood of the local economy.

One promising way to revive America’s manufacturing might is not by going big but by going small – and going local. Digitally-assisted manufacturing technologies, such as 3D printing, have the potential to launch a new generation of manufacturing startups producing customized, locally-designed goods in a way overseas mega-factories can’t match. To jumpstart this revolution, we need to provide local manufacturing entrepreneurs with access to the latest technologies to test out their ideas. The Grassroots Manufacturing Act would create federally-supported centers offering budding entrepreneurs and small and medium-sized firms access to the latest 3D printing and robotics equipment.

 

THE CHALLENGE: NEXT-GENERATION U.S. MANUFACTURING NEEDS A JUMPSTART.

The collapse in manufacturing employment and wages drove a stake through the heart of America. Conventional factories making commodity high-volume products could not compete with mega-sized plants in low-wage countries. That’s why many of America’s largest and most productive plants have closed or shrunk sharply since 2000, devastating many less dense areas where local factories were the main source of jobs.

Yet, for all the talk of an intangible data-driven economy, physical industries such as manufacturing and agriculture are still essential to prosperity – especially outside our largest cities. These are, however, precisely the industries where investment, incomes, and jobs have lagged behind, hurting millions of working Americans across the country.

U.S. manufacturing productivity is lagging.

One problem is that many small and medium-size factories have been stuck with old technologies and aging equipment because the owners don’t have the funds to modernize. As a result, productivity in U.S. factories has lagged, the price charged by domestic factories has risen, and the penetration of Chinese products into domestic markets has continued to increase. In 2017, imports from China, adjusted for inflation, rose by 9.4 percent. By comparison, the gross output of U.S. factories rose by only 2.2 percent.

Digitally-assisted manufacturing is the wave of the future, but investment in these technologies is also lagging.

Digitally-assisted manufacturing technologies are potentially game changers for U.S. manufacturing. Local factories using 3D printing, robotics, or similar advances could,for instance, produce customized and locally-designed products – better-fitting clothing, more-comfortable furniture, and customized equipment for businesses – at a price overseas mega-factories can’t match.

Moreover, there’s increasing evidence that digitization can open up new markets and create new jobs. Even the most automated technologies require loads of skilled workers to do the more complicated tasks machines can’t handle. Indeed, the newest term is “cobots” – collaborative robots designed to work with humans (rather than replace them).

Despite these potential rewards, however, the U.S. risks falling behind in this crucial race for next-generation manufacturing. The America Competes Act of 2010 authorized federal loan guarantees for small or medium-sized manufacturers for the use or production of innovative technologies. But no such loan guarantees have been issued.

The Manufacturing Extension Partnership is an excellent program, but its FY2018 funding of $140 million is 15 percent lower, in real terms, than its funding in 1998. The American Innovation and Competitiveness Act of 2017, signed in the last days of the Obama Administration, does offer limited funding for a couple of centers to explore automated manufacturing. However, that’s not enough for a country the size of the United States – not when Japan and Germany are putting much more money into pushing their manufacturing sectors into the future.

Now is the time to beef up our current support for local manufacturing entrepreneurs and create a new wave of digitally-assisted, high-wage manufacturing jobs around the country.

 

THE GOAL: CREATE 50,000 ADDITIONAL MANUFACTURING STARTUPS OVER THE NEXT FOUR YEARS USING DIGITALLY-ASSISTED TECHNOLOGIES – AND ONE MILLION NEW JOBS.

Digitally-assisted manufacturing technologies will boost productivity, cut costs, and increase flexibility. In the process, that will open up new markets for customized and semi-customized goods.
We advocate a national push to create 50,000 new manufacturing startups across the country to encourage the rebirth of American manufacturing ingenuity at the local level. If each startup employs 20 people, on average, that will mean one million new jobs. The goal is to get scale on new production technologies across the country – not just in one or two centers. We are not talking about industrial policy, or protectionism, or bringing back old and dying industries. Rather, the goal is to help accelerate the next wave of manufacturing prosperity.

 

THE PLAN: SEED THE CREATION OF STATE AND LOCAL DIGITAL MANUFACTURING CENTERS AND SUPPORT BUDDING MANUFACTURING ENTREPRENEURS.

We advocate a three-part program:

1. Increase access to technology.

It’s essential to provide local manufacturing entrepreneurs access to the latest technologies to test out their ideas. We propose a Manufacturing Grassroots Act that would offer state and local governments funds to set up centers with the latest 3D printing and robotics equipment – along with all the necessary software and training. Budding entrepreneurs and small businesses can apply for access on an “all-comers” basis, to give everyone an opportunity to get in on the ground floor of wealth creation.

2. Guarantee federal loans.

Existing small and medium-size manufacturers need help getting funding for the adoption of the new technologies. That means federal loan guarantees, based on the existing but unutilized program mentioned earlier from the 2010 America Competes Act. It may also mean setting up a new program for low-interest loans to manufacturers who want to digitize.

3. Fund federal research.

At the national level, Congress should budget $300 million to fund federal research to develop the underlying standards for online manufacturing platforms, just like the government developed the underlying standards for the Internet. This work is already going on, but it needs to be accelerated.

ENDNOTES

Michael Mandel, “The Rise of the Internet of Goods: A New Perspective on the Digital Future for Manufacturers,” Progressive Policy Institute and Manufacturers Alliance for Productivity and Innovation, August 2018.

New Ideas for a Do-Something Congress No. 1: “A Check on Trump’s Reckless Tariffs”

Article I, Section 8 of the Constitution sets out Congress’s job description on international trade, empowering it “to lay and collect . . . duties” and “to regulate commerce with foreign nations.”

For the past two years, Congress hasn’t been doing its job. Instead, it’s stood by while President Trump has hijacked its constitutional trade powers and recklessly imposed damaging tariffs. Trump’s abuse of trade powers delegated to him by Congress is destroying U.S. jobs, hammering large and small businesses, increasing prices for American families, and prompting foreign retaliation against American manufactured and farm exports.

It’s time for Congress to start doing its job on trade. A key step is enacting the Trade Authority Protection (TAP) Act. This balanced legislation would rein in Trump’s abuse of delegated trade powers, require greater presidential accountability, and enable Congress to nullify irresponsible tariffs and trade restrictions.

 

THE CHALLENGE: PRESIDENT TRUMP’S ABUSE OF DELEGATED POWERS ON TARIFFS AND TRADE IS HARMING AMERICAN BUSINESSES, WORKERS, AND CONSUMERS.

President Trump’s reckless tariffs are damaging America’s economy and U.S. trade relations.
From Maine lobstermen(1) to West Coast dockworkers (2), and for countless workers, farmers, manufacturers (3), and consumers nationwide, President Trump’s tariffs—and resulting foreign retaliation—are causing serious and growing economic pain. Workers are losing jobs (4), manufacturing is being offshored (5), and farmers worry about rotting crops and lost export markets (6). America’s families are paying more for everything from washers and dryers to couches, clothing, canned beer, Christmas lights, and car insurance, while higher costs for infrastructure projects are straining local budgets (7). And unfocused tariffs against allies make it harder for America to mount joint action against serious trade threats, especially China’s technology theft and state subsidies (8).

In taking these irresponsible actions, the President is abusing trade powers delegated to him by Congress. Congress has done nothing to rein in Trump’s reckless trade wars and his hijacking of its constitutional trade authority.

Past presidents have prudently used trade powers delegated by Congress.
The Constitution provides Congress with primary authority over tariffs and foreign trade (9). For the first 145 years under the Constitution, Congress employed these powers directly through legislation. After the disastrous Smoot-Hawley tariffs deepened the Great Depression, Congress wisely adopted a different approach (10).

Beginning with the Reciprocal Trade Agreement Act of 1934,11 Congress increasingly delegated authority to the president to negotiate trade deals, adjust tariffs, and enforce U.S. trade rights (12). In effect, while retaining its constitutional trade powers and oversight authority, Congress has “subcontracted” key trade functions to the president.

These delegations make sense under America’s constitutional system. A 535-member Congress isn’t particularly well equipped to set tariffs, bargain on trade agreements, or enforce trade rules.

Presidents of both parties have largely exercised delegated trade powers responsibly, working constructively with Congress to expand trade (13). When President Kennedy signed the Trade Expansion Act of 1962—which authorized the president to impose trade restrictions to address “national security” threats—he emphasized building alliances and reducing trade barriers, and warned against “stagnating behind tariff walls” (14).

President Trump has abused delegated tariff and trade powers.
Unlike his bipartisan predecessors,15 Donald Trump hasn’t been a prudent steward of delegated trade powers. Rather, he’s cynically abused delegated authority, believing, for example, that simply invoking “national security” enables him to take virtually any action to restrict trade (16).

In imposing tariffs on imports of steel and aluminum, President Trump has used “national security” as little more than a pretext. Long-time trade experts note that the Administration’s investigations in these cases were “extremely non-transparent” and that its security and economic analyses were “embarrassingly feeble” and “absurd” (17).

Since adopting the metals tariffs, the Administration has implemented an exemption process that’s been chaotic, opaque, and lacking essential due process—especially for thousands of small businesses harmed by the tariffs. Applicants rarely get relief. The process seems designed, instead, to preserve tariffs for the Administration’s well-connected cronies in the primary metals sector (18).

Trump is doubling down on abusive “national security” cases, pushing for national security duties on auto imports from U.S. allies, despite near-universal opposition. The Administration’s public hearing in this investigation has been called a “show trial” intended to justify the President’s pre-ordained auto tariffs (19).

The Administration is abusing other delegated trade authorities. In a vital “Section 301” investigation of China’s theft of U.S. hi-tech, Trump initially sought to change China’s conduct by imposing unilateral tariffs on $50 billion in Chinese imports—based on faulty advice that China wouldn’t retaliate. When China retaliated, Trump impulsively increased the tariffed imports by another $200 billion and has threatened duties on all $500 billion in U.S. imports from China (20).

Trump’s irresponsible actions regarding China appear to be driven more by whim than any real strategy. It’s no surprise that his unfocused tariffs haven’t caused China to budge (21).

 

THE GOAL: REIGN IN PRESIDENT TRUMP’S ABUSE OF DELEGATED POWERS WHILE PRESERVING A RESPONSIBLE BALANCE BETWEEN CONGRESS AND THE PRESIDENT ON TRADE

President Trump is seriously abusing trade powers “subcontracted” to him by Congress. Accordingly, like any responsible general contractor, Congress must step in and better oversee how the president uses delegated trade powers.

Most importantly, Congress needs an effective procedure for stopping reckless trade restrictions by the president—and reversing damaging tariffs on hundreds of billions in imports that Trump has already enacted. Any new mechanism should apply to the full range of trade restrictions—including tariffs, quotas, and import prohibitions—and to the full list of laws that authorize the president to restrict trade.

At the same time, Congress shouldn’t return to the role of setting tariffs, negotiating trade deals, or enforcing trade rules. And, the president must still have authority to take initiative to restrict trade for legitimate reasons, subject to effective congressional oversight.

 

THE SOLUTION: ENACT THE TRADE AUTHORITY PROTECTION ACT

The bipartisan Trade Authority Protection Act would establish a process to enable Congress to evaluate and, if necessary nullify, the president’s use of trade powers delegated by Congress. (The TAP Act was introduced in May 2018 by Reps. Ron Kind (D-WI), Gregory Meeks (D-NY), Ralph Norman (R-SC) and Charles Dent (R-PA)) (22).

Under the TAP Act, 60 days before any “congressionally delegated trade action” could go into effect, the president would be required to submit a report to Congress on the proposed action. The report would describe the proposed action and its economic impacts, including the impacts of potential foreign retaliation. The Act would also require the Government Accountability Office—the investigative arm of Congress—to report on whether the proposed action complies with applicable law.

The TAP Act defines “congressionally delegated trade actions” broadly, to include tariffs, quotas, and import prohibitions under a range of laws that empower the President to restrict trade (23).

The Act would establish a procedure—like the Congressional Review Act (24) process for reviewing major regulations—to enable Congress to nullify the President’s proposed trade action. To do so, Congress would use an expedited process to pass a resolution disapproving the President’s proposed action within the 60-day review period.

The TAP Act would also require, in the first year after any trade action takes effect, that the U.S. International Trade Commission conduct a comprehensive assessment for Congress of the economic effects of the action on U.S. producers and consumers.

Finally, since the TAP Act was introduced in May 2018, President Trump has used delegated powers to impose reckless and damaging tariffs on hundreds of billions of dollars of imports, often using highly questionable legal and economic justifications. To assure these past actions are fully evaluated and reviewed by Congress, it’s vital that the original TAP Act be amended to assure that its reporting and nullification requirements apply retroactively to past Administration actions.

 

ENDNOTES

1 Shawn Donnan, Even Lobsters Can’t Escape Trump’s Trade War, Bloomberg, Nov. 7, 2018, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/features/2018-11-07/even-lobsters-can-t-escape-trump-s-trade-war?cmpid=socialflow-twitter-businessweek&utm_source=twitter&utm_content=businessweek&utm_medium=social&utm_campaign=socialflow-organic.

2 Jeff Stein, ‘People are worried and people are scared.’ These workers are hurt by Trump’s trade war, but ineligible for his bailout, Washington Post, Oct. 24, 2018, https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/economy/hurt-by-trumps-trade-war-ineligible-for-a-bailout/2018/10/24/7f30d866-ce67-11e8-a360-85875bac0b1f_story.html?utm_term=.5d8bc2ddefd.

3 Keith Naughton and Joe Deaux, Ford’s Hinrichs says Trump tariffs make U.S. steel costliest in the world, Automotive News, Oct. 22, 2018, https://www.autonews.com/article/20181022/OEM01/181029915/trump-tariffs-ford-hinrichs-stel; Rick Barrett, As tariffs continue, panic begins to sink in among Wisconsin manufacturers, Journal Sentinel, Oct. 22, 2018, https://www.jsonline.com/story/money/2018/10/22/tariffs-boats-cribs-bourbon-more-rattle-wisonsin-manufacturers/1686445002/.

4 Trump Trade War—Mid Continent Nail facing closure over tariffs, Steel News, Oct. 16, 2018, https://steelguru.com/steel/trump-trade-war-mid-continent-nail-facing-closure-over-tariffs/523502.

5 Bob Bryan, A Chicago-area manufacturer is laying off 153 workers and moving to Mexico partly because of Trump’s tariffs, Business Insider, Aug. 15, 2018, https://www.businessinsider.com/trump-tariffs-trade-war-causes-150-layoffs-at-chicago-manufacturer-2018-8.

6 Binyamin Appelbaum, Their Soybeans Piling Up, Farmers Hope Trade War Ends Before Beans Rot, New York Times, Nov. 5, 2018, https://www.nytimes.com/2018/11/05/business/soybeans-farmers-trade-war.html#click=https://t.co/iTW7QnQWbT.

7 Ed Gerwin, The ‘Trump Trade Tax’ Strikes Out America’s Baseball Fans, Progressive Policy Institute, Jul. 17, 2018, https://www.progressivepolicy.org/blog/the-trump-trade-tax-strikes-out-americas-baseball-fan//; Doug Palmer, Trump’s tariffs put pressure on insurance companies and premiums, Politico Morning Trade, Nov. 5, 2018, https://www.politico.com/newsletters/morning-trade/2018/11/05/trumps-tariffs-put-pressure-on-insurance-companies-and-premiums-400272; Infrastructure Construction Projects Stalled on Trump Tariffs, Yahoo, Jul. 18, 2018, https://www.forconstructionpros.com/business/news/21014043/infrastructure-construction-projects-stalled-on-trump-tariffs.

8 Ed Gerwin, Confronting China’s Threat to Open Trade, Progressive Policy Institute, Jun. 20, 2018, https://www.progressivepolicy.org/publications/confronting-chinas-threat-to-open-trade/.

9 U.S. Constitution, Art. I, Sec. 8, https://www.law.cornell.edu/constitution/articlei.

10 Bill Krist, Did the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Cause the Great Depression? America’s Trade Policy, Washington International Trade Association, Jun. 16, 2014, https://americastradepolicy.com/did-the-smoot-hawley-tariff-cause-the-great-depression/#.W-xJ3y2ZOCQ.

11 U.S. House of Representatives, Historical Highlights: The Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1943, https://history.house.gov/HistoricalHighlight/Detail/36918.

12 Office of the U.S. Trade Representative, Eighty Years After the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act, Tradewinds, Jun. 2014, https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/blog/2014/June/Eighty-years-of-the-Reciprocal-Trade-Agreements-Act.

13 Rep. Ron Kind, Congress must defend role in international trade, The Hill, Jun. 7, 2018, https://thehill.com/blogs/congress-blog/economy-budget/391230-congress-must-defend-role-in-international-trade.

14 John F. Kennedy, Remarks Upon Signing the Trade Expansion Act, Oct. 11, 1962,
https://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/documents/remarks-upon-signing-the-trade-expansion-act.

15 Previous presidents, for example, responsibly limited their use of “national security” trade powers to matters that raise legitimate security concerns. David Wassel, Section 232: A splendid little trade war, The Hill, Mar. 17, 2018, https://thehill.com/opinion/finance/378290-section-232-a-splendid-little-trade-war.

16 Paul Krugman, Trump’s Manchurian Trade Policy, New York Times, May 28, 2018, https://www.nytimes.com/2018/05/28/opinion/trump-china-trade-policy.html; It’s telling that President Trump often ignores the pretext of “national security,” and admits that the real purpose of his purported security tariffs is to provide leverage against trade partners on other trade priorities. Michael C. Bender, Rebecca Ballhaus, Peter Nicholas, and Alex Leary, Trump Steps Up Attacks on Fed Chairman Jerome Powell, Wall Street Journal, Oct. 12, 2018, https://www.wsj.com/articles/trump-steps-up-attacks-on-fed-chairman-jerome-powell-1540338090?mod=hp_lead_pos.

17 Chad P. Bown, Trump has announced massive aluminum and steel tariffs, Here are 5 things you need to know. Washington Post, Mar. 3, 2018, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/monkey-cage/wp/2018/03/01/trump-has-announced-massive-aluminum-and-steel-tariffs-here-are-5-things-you-need-to-know/?utm_term=.c88a87214dda; Phil Levy, The Commerce Department Makes A Feeble National Security Plea For Steel Protection, Forbes, Feb. 16, 2018, https://www.forbes.com/sites/phillevy/2018/02/16/the-commerce-departments-feeble-national-security-plea-for-steel-protection/#40bbede842dc.

18 Megan Keller, Commerce Department IG to audit Trump’s tariff exemptions, The Hill, Nov. 1, 2018, https://thehill.com/policy/finance/414193-commerce-department-inspector-general-audits-tariff-exemption-process; Ed Gerwin, Off-the-rails trade policy shows how America loses under Trump, The Hill, Sept. 18, 2018, https://thehill.com/opinion/finance/407179-off-the-rails-trade-war-shows-how-america-loses-under-trump.

19 Ana Swanson, On Trump’s Car Tariffs, Companies are United in Dissent, New York Times, Jul. 19, 2018, https://www.nytimes.com/2018/07/19/us/politics/trump-car-import-tariffs.html; Jennifer Jacobs and Jenny Leonard, U.S. Car-Import Probe Advances as Trump Plans Trade Meeting, Bloomberg, Nov. 12, 2018, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2018-11-12/u-s-car-import-probe-advances-as-trump-plans-trade-team-meeting.

20 Louis Nelson, Victoria Guida, and Adam Behsudi, Trump threatens tariffs on all $500 billion worth of Chinese imports, Politico, Jul. 20. 2018, https://www.politico.com/story/2018/07/20/trump-china-tariffs-734938.

21 Anna Fifield, China’s trade surplus with the U.S. hit a record $34.1 billion in September amid trade war, Washington Post, Oct. 12, 2018, https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/chinas-trade-surplus-with-the-us-hit-a-record-341-billion-in-september-amid-trade-war/2018/10/12/acdb7412-cdd9-11e8-a360-85875bac0b1f_story.html?utm_term=.f9d7beaa6bda.

22 Trade Authority Protection Act, H.R. 5760, 115th Cong., 2nd Sess., https://www.congress.gov/bill/115th-congress/house-bill/5760/text; Congressman Ron Kind, Bipartisan Group of Lawmakers Call for Implementation of Congressional Review Act Procedures on Trade Measures, Press Release, May 10, 2018, https://kind.house.gov/media-center/press-releases/bipartisan-group-lawmakers-call-implementation-congressional-review-act.

23 Ibid.

24 U.S. Government Accountability Office, Congressional Review Act, https://www.gao.gov/legal/other-legal-work/congressional-review-act.

Mandel for Forbes, “Why 2019 Will Be The Year Of The Manufacturing Platform”

The big tech platforms get all the attention these days. But the biggest tech news of 2019 may turn out to be the rise of the manufacturing platforms—companies that rewrite the rules of production and product development, and in the process create new opportunities for local manufacturing.

The economic backdrop is the looming threat of an all-out U.S-China trade war, which places a new premium on domestic sourcing. If trade tensions get worse, highly-scaleable manufacturing platforms will make it much easier for companies and entrepreneurs to open up new factories in the United States and plug them right into the platform.

In many ways manufacturing platforms are the logical outgrowth of existing trends towards outsourcing and factoryless production. Manufacturers have been increasingly separating product design and marketing from the actual production process for years.

Continue reading at Forbes.

Misguided Crew Size Legislation Risks Slowing Needed Freight Rail Growth

The Progressive Policy Institute (PPI) has previously opposed arbitrary, redundant, and costly regulations, and proposed the Regulatory Improvement Commission to eliminate them. Regulation plays a vital role in refereeing market competition, protecting public health and safety, and keeping powerful economic actors honest. But regulations must be more nimble and adaptable to catalyze growth in a fast-changing world.

For people skeptical that regulation inhibits innovation and productivity growth, here’s an example of a wrong-headed proposed rule that would put Washington in the business of micromanaging employment in the freight rail sector.

When the Rail Safety Improvement Act was passed following the 2008 Chatsworth train collision, it mandated freight railroads implement Positive Train Control (PTC). PTC is a nationwide system of newly developed technologies that constantly processes thousands of variables to avert human error, including train collisions and derailments. Its implementation came at a hefty price to the railroads, estimated to cost more than $10 billion by completion.

One of the benefits of PTC was that it would enable railroads to move from two-person to one-person crews at some point down the road, boosting productivity with no loss of safety.

However, lawmakers now appear eager to flip course as fears of automation and job loss loom large in public policy conversations. Earlier this year, the Safe Freight Act was introduced in the Senate, a companion bill to a bipartisan House proposal unveiled in 2017. The legislation would mandate the crew size of freight trains to include both a locomotive engineer and a train conductor. While the legislation will not pass before midterms, it is likely to be reintroduced next Congress.

These proposals would deny freight rail the productivity gains of the digital age despite the widespread embrace of automation for passenger vehicles and commercial trucks on highways. Labor productivity for rail transportation has risen only a modest 16 percent over the last decade, about the same as the lagging pace of productivity growth across the entire U.S. economy. Meanwhile, as shown in Figure 1, the price of railroad transportation has risen 77 percent since 2000, far outpacing inflation. Allowing the freight rail industry to digitize would jumpstart productivity growth and cut distribution costs for the energy, manufacturing, and construction sectors they serve.

What’s more, there is no evidence to suggest that one-person crews are less safe than two-person crews. Single-person crews are commonly used in other countries and the FRA acknowledges the “evidence…indicates that safety record of these foreign operations are acceptable.” In the U.S., crew sizes have steadily been reduced from the five-person crews of the 1970s to the current two-person crews, with accident rates falling more than 80 percent during that time. And passenger trains have safely used single-person crews for decades.

Railroad investment and technological advances have played a critical role in realizing safety gains over the last decade. Since 2008, freight railroads have spent $245.3 billion on capital expenditures like infrastructure and equipment. Ultrasound, ground-penetrating radar, smart sensors, analytics software, and data sharing have enabled railroads to proactively identify and fix track and equipment issues. As a result, railroad accidents are at a historic low, according to data from the FRA. As shown in the figure below, the total train accident rate dropped 42 percent from 2007 to 2017. Track-caused accidents have dropped 51 percent. And accidents caused by human error are down 41 percent.

The implementation of PTC promises to further drop accident rates. According to forecasts from the Federal Highway Administration, total U.S. freight shipments will rise from 17.7 billion tons in 2016 to 24.2 billion tons in 2040, a 37 percent increase. Imposing crew size mandates on the freight rail industry would inefficiently divert resources from investing in safety, cutting costs for consumers, and improving and expanding America’s rail infrastructure. Rather, it would unnecessarily increase labor costs in the safest era ever of rail travel.

Yarrow for SF Chronicle, “Update labor laws to meet needs of ‘gig’ economy”

I write this article as a freelancer. I take Lyft to get around. I’ve booked an apartment this summer through Airbnb. I’ve been an adjunct professor. I’ve just gotten estimates for roof and other home repairs from men who work for themselves.

All of these activities are part of a large universe of what’s come to be called the “gig economy” in America, the contentious subject of a U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics report released Thursday.

The study found that about 15.5 million Americans work in contingent, or short-term, jobs and/or in “alternative work arrangements,” including as independent contractors, on-call workers, temporary agency workers, and workers sent out on jobs by contract firms. A majority of these workers is men, and African Americans and Hispanics are disproportionately represented in the lowest-paid sectors of the gig economy. Sara Horowitz, founder of the Freelancers Union, says that 55 million Americans are independent workers, and the Government Accountability Office puts the number even higher. “Establishing a statistical definition of the gig economy is no easy task,” as a 2016 Congressional Research Service report said.

Whatever the number, the gig economy is a sign of the growing precariousness of work in America. With artificial intelligence and other technologies threatening to further reduce the need for full-time workers, it’s imperative that labor law and social policies change.

Continue reading at San Francisco Chronicle.

Guaranteed Jobs: Too Big to Succeed

As the party out of power, Democrats have the luxury of thinking big as they consider how to topple President Donald Trump in 2020. Bold, ambitious ideas are what the party sorely needs if it is to capture voters’ attention and woo them from Trump’s corrosive grip.

But if Democrats are to craft a winning agenda for 2020, bigness and boldness alone are insufficient; political feasibility and substantive plausibility are also necessary ingredients. That’s why the latest big and bold idea catching the eye of potential 2020 contenders – a federal jobs guarantee – is ultimately a disappointment.

Touted by advocates as a way to achieve “permanent full employment,” the notion of a federally guaranteed job for anyone who wants one has won support from three rumored presidential hopefuls so far, including New York Sen. Kirsten Gillibrand, Vermont Sen. Bernie Sanders and New Jersey Sen. Cory Booker. Last week, Booker revealed draft legislation to pilot a federal jobs guarantee program in up to 15 localities nationwide, while Sanders has floated a much more ambitious national plan focused on public works projects at a scale not seen since the Great Depression. Under both proposals, participants would earn wages of up to $15 an hour, along with benefits such as paid family and sick leave and health insurance. “There is great dignity in work – and in America, if you want to provide for your family, you should be able to find a full-time job that pays a fair wage,” said Booker in a press release announcing his effort.

Booker’s endorsement speaks to the inherent surface appeal of a jobs guarantee. To borrow President Bill Clinton’s famous formulation, Americans who “work hard and play by the rules” deserve a shot at self-sufficiency, and the promise of work for all who want it invokes Americans’ innate sense of fair play. Proponents also rightly point out stark disparities in employment between certain groups, the result of discrimination and other structural barriers that guaranteed access to meaningful employment could arguably remedy.

Unfortunately, the idea also suffers from a variety of fatal defects, including its size, timing and relevance and any number of practical obstacles that make it administratively unworkable as well as politically untenable. For one thing, it rests on the dubious assumption that the American electorate – at a time when public cynicism and distrust toward government remain at all-time highs– is ready to embrace a dramatically expanded role for the federal government as the nation’s largest staffing agency and employer. More fundamentally, the idea betrays a deep lack of faith in the inherent resilience of the American economy and its people to weather disruption and change. Most Americans don’t share the left’s inordinate confidence in government’s ability to engineer shared prosperity from the top down. Aggressive advocacy of a panacea like government guaranteed jobs can only reinforce public impressions that progressives will always default to “big government” as the solution to complex economic problems.


While a federal jobs guarantee certainly passes the “bigness” test, its very bigness is a central conceptual weakness, at least in the current political environment. It is far too large a hammer in search of a nail.

According to the leading proposal for a national guaranteed jobs program, it would cost roughly $543 billion a year to create 10.7 million new federal jobs covering every worker unemployed or underemployed in January 2018 (a figure known as “U.6”). That would put the number of job guarantee participants at nearly five times the size of the entire current federal workforce.

It’s hard to fathom why proponents believe there is public appetite for a jobs program of this scale today, especially given that the nation’s official unemployment rate is at its lowest in nearly 20 years, employers in many places are complaining of worker shortages, the economy is set to grow at a solid pace and fears of inflation are currently preoccupying central bankers and financial markets. And even though workforce participation is lower than it could or should be compared to historical standards, the magnitude of unemployment and underemployment is nowhere near what it was the last time a massive federal works program was proposed and implemented, which was during the Great Depression. Then, unemployment rates were running at upwards of 15 to 25 percent while the private sector was wholly crippled.

Though some proponents might imagine an automation apocalypse that could ultimately throw millions of Americans out of work, talking about a national jobs guarantee program now is, at best, still wildly premature. Moreover, even if such a circumstance should occur, it’s far from settled that Americans would prefer a large-scale public jobs program over other strategies to manage economic disruption, including, heaven forfend, their own abilities to learn new skills and adapt to change.

A second and more serious conceptual flaw with a jobs guarantee is that it seeks to solve the wrong problem. While the lack of jobs is a continuing concern for some groups in some areas and absolutely should not be overlooked, the biggest malady ailing the middle and working classes isn’t so much the quantity of jobs as their quality – in the form of stagnant wages, declining benefits and the loss of stability and security. In this context, a national jobs guarantee program isn’t just too big a hammer, but the wrong tool altogether.

Though wages are finally ticking upward, the long-term trend toward stagnation is still far from being erased. The Brookings Institution, for example, reports that real wages for the middle quintile of workers grew by only 3.4 percent between 1979 and 2016, while labor’s share of national income has also steadily fallen despite healthy corporate profits. More Americans are also losing access to traditional employer-provided benefits, such as health insurance. At the same time that the share of employers offering health insurance has dropped by 10 percentage points since 1999, according to the Kaiser Foundation, more Americans are finding themselves to be no longer employees at all but members of the ever-precarious “gig economy.”

Though wages are finally ticking upward, the long-term trend toward stagnation is still far from being erased

Especially vulnerable are the workers with the least amount
of education, the one group that has remained consistently underemployed despite rising fortunes for others. In March, for instance, just 44 percent of Americans without a high school diploma were working, compared to 72.6 percent for college graduates. While a jobs guarantee program could potentially help some of these less-educated workers, a big question is why they should be shunted to relatively low-skilled public jobs rather than given the opportunity to increase their skills and compete for skilled openings
currently going begging.

As for the question of wages, proponents of a job guarantee argue their plan would put upward pressure on wages by forcing private sector employers to compete for workers. This argument, however, rests on a very large and unproven assumption: that enough workers would in fact prefer a “public option” over private sector work to create that pressure. Many workers, for instance, might choose a lower-paid private sector job in the short term with the potential for advancement in the future, rather than a public job capped at $15 an hour into perpetuity. In any event, the potential impact on private sector wages would be indirect at best when other, more targeted ideas could have broader impact on workers’ incomes and financial security.


Even setting aside the conceptual and political weaknesses of a federal jobs guarantee, any number of practical obstacles could also prove insurmountable.

For instance, one such practical question is the kind of jobs government would provide. Booker’s proposal, for instance, imagines that participants would work in fields that are “currently under-provided, like child and elder care, infrastructure, and community revitalization.” What’s not clear, however, is how the government will gauge demand in a particular sector so it will know how many workers to deploy. Also unanswered are where and how to place them. These are not questions in which the federal government has a proven track record, particularly given the limited success of the more than 40 employment and job training programs the federal government already administers. If, for example, the government miscalculates and produces a surplus of elder care providers in a community with an insufficient number of potential patients, what would these workers do?

The new corps of government workers will not be fungible from one field to another, given the skills required for each of these professions, as well as licensing and other requirements. Workers cannot be working in a nursing home on one day and on a road crew the next, depending on demand.

A second set of practical concerns involves the role of the private sector and the effect these new federal workers would have on labor markets. While job guarantee advocates seek to create a new “floor” in the labor market and prompt the private sector to raise its own wages to compete for workers, it’s not clear that this is, in fact, what would happen. What could occur, however, is the displacement of private sector providers of child care, elder care and other services if the federal government ends up competing directly with existing employers. While some may not find this outcome objectionable if big companies were the ones to face the most pressure, the reality is that small businesses – such as home-based day care centers – are the least likely to survive in the face of government competition.

A third set of worries involves the preparation of workers for the jobs they would be asked to do. Current job guarantee proposals seem to assume that anyone who wants a job also has the skills and capacity to perform it, which is unrealistic. While the simple lack of available work might be all that stymies many workers, many other Americans who want to work face far more serious barriers, including the lack of skills, mental and physical disabilities that limit their capacity, caregiving obligations, mental health concerns or other issues that will need to be overcome if full-time employment is to be a reality.

Barriers like these are especially problematic if a federal work program is focused on infrastructure projects, as Sanders proposes. Though liberals romanticize the Civilian Conservation Corps and other Depression-era federal work efforts, infrastructure jobs often involve physically demanding outdoor labor in all sorts of weather, along with grueling hours. They are not for everyone.

One way to gauge the scope of the challenge around potential participants’ employability is to examine the ranks of workers “marginally attached” to the workforce, defined by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) as those who want to work and have looked for work in the last 12 months or those available to work but who have not searched for work in the last four weeks. These workers would presumably be prime targets for a federal jobs guarantee program.

Among the 1.59 million workers considered “marginally attached” in 2017, less than a third reported being “discouraged over job prospects,” while the vast majority cited other reasons for not being in the labor force, such as the lack of child care or transportation, “ill health or disability,” and family responsibilities.

If the purpose of a federal jobs program is to provide safety net employment for workers who cannot otherwise find private sector jobs, such an effort cannot succeed unless it also helps workers overcome the very barriers that made private sector work tougher for them to attain. This means the government not only needs to provide jobs, it needs to provide training so that workers can competently perform the work they’re given; affordable child care and transportation; remedial help if necessary with basic literacy and numeracy as well as so-called “soft skills”; mental health services and other accommodations. All of these are immensely complex, expensive and time-consuming services. But if the federal government is not willing to provide or at least subsidize these services, the “guarantee” of a job is meaningless unless there is some assurance of a worker’s potential success. And even then, there are a host of unanswered questions about the worker’s end of the bargain. Can a worker with a guaranteed job be fired? What if an employee is guilty of malfeasance or simply can’t perform? What rights and duties does a “guarantee” create?

Finally, there is the consideration of cost.

As mentioned above, the large-scale national job program envisioned by its leading proponents would cost $543 billion, or 3 percent of GDP, to employ 10.7 million people. This translates to a per-worker cost of $50,747 a year – or just slightly below the median household income in 2016 of $57,617. By comparison, federal spending on Social Security totaled $922 billion in 2016 while benefiting 61 million people, a relative bargain by comparison.

The $543 billion figure is also situated in the context of relatively low unemployment. At the height of the recession in 2010, the total share of workers unemployed and underemployed (“U.6”) was 17.1 percent, meaning that the cost of a federal jobs program could expect to double in a downturn, to more than $1 trillion a year.

Spending of this magnitude would crowd out spending on a host of other priorities that might be better suited to building human and social capital, such as improving early childhood and K-12 education, expanding health care or making college and occupational training more affordable. Worse yet, funding for a federal jobs program could come at the expense of other safety net programs supporting children, disabled Americans and others who cannot work. As Ernie Tedeschi, an economist who served under President Barack Obama recently told The Washington Post, “It would be extremely expensive, and I wonder if this is the best, most targeted use of the amount of money it would cost.”


At the same time that a federal jobs guarantee program is too big, it paradoxically also aims too low. Federally provided jobs are unlikely to be the kind of jobs that people want, nor would there necessarily be a path to upward mobility for those relegated to this work. While a federal jobs program might promise the dignity of work for all, what is delivered could still be work without dignity.

As envisioned by its advocates, the kinds of jobs the federal government could provide include such tasks as “the repair, maintenance, and expansion of the nation’s infrastructure, housing stock, and public buildings,” “assistance with ecological restoration,” “engagement in community development projects,” as well as jobs in child care, education and senior care.

Compared to the private sector, the federal government is relatively ill-suited to the task of creating jobs that demand workers’ creativity, innovation and commitment

While there is value in all of this work, the ranks of America’s unemployed and underemployed deserve better. Compared to the private sector, the federal government is relatively ill-suited to the task of creating jobs that demand workers’ creativity, innovation and commitment, that best fit the needs of the local and national economy at any given time and, importantly, are self-sustaining.

With many fewer dollars than a jobs guarantee program would cost, the federal government should invest in other, more effective ways to spur the creation of high-quality jobs, prepare workers for well-paying careers with opportunities for advancement and supplement the wages of the working poor.

Among the myriad of possibilities for increasing incomes is to expand the federal Earned Income Tax Credit for low-wage workers, in combination with raising the minimum wage, as Isabel Sawhill and Quentin Karpilow of the Brookings Institution recommend. Another possibility is to eliminate the payroll tax, which falls most heavily on low-wage workers as well as the self-employed, and replace it with a broad-based value-added tax (VAT) of the kind adopted in most European countries or a carbon tax, which would have the additional benefit of combating climate change.

Another option, which PPI has endorsed, is to help workers earn better wages by expanding the availability of Pell grants to students pursuing high-quality occupational credentials in IT, advanced manufacturing and other “new-collar” careers where demand is growing. This idea would allow older, lower-income and displaced workers who do not want or cannot afford to go to college with an alternative means of upgrading their skills. Government should also invest heavily in rural broadband to expand digital opportunity to all corners of the country and help rural areas decimated by the loss of manufacturing and mining jobs reinvent themselves and attract new industry. Government could also encourage new models of corporate governance and ownership, such as the “benefit corporation” model PPI has embraced, or the expansion of employee stock ownership plans (“ESOPS”), that would ensure that more of the fruits of economic growth flow to workers.

The advocates of guaranteed jobs have their finger on the right problem: far too many Americans are suffering from the maldistribution – or outright denial – of economic opportunity. But by making work a right – as a guaranteed job would do – the government would also paradoxically be diminishing its value. The fundamental nature of the American character is to strive, to achieve – and to earn. What the government should guarantee, then, is not a job but the means and opportunity for all Americans to attain their aspirations to the fullest.

Are Democrats Really the Party of Fiscal Responsibility? (Part 2)

Earlier this week, we published a blog exploring the relationship between budget deficits and unemployment under both Democratic and Republican presidents over the last 40 years. Our analysis found that deficits under Democratic presidents rose and fell with unemployment (which is what should happen when adhering to responsible counter-cyclical fiscal policy), while deficits under Republican presidents did not. Moreover, we found that deficits under Democratic presidents were consistently lower than those under Republican presidents facing comparable economic circumstances. Below is a chart depicting the data upon which our analysis was based:

Following the blog’s publication, a lively discussion ensued on Twitter over how much credit a president deserves for the fiscal situation on their watch. Marc Goldwein of the Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget and Brian Riedl of the Manhattan Institute rightly pointed out that Congress plays a major role in crafting federal fiscal policy and should be taken into consideration when adjudicating fiscal records by party.

As a result, we decided to make a second chart that focused on partisan control of Congress instead of the White House. The underlying data is the same as the chart above, with the exception of projections for 2019 and 2020, which were removed because nobody knows what the composition of Congress will look like after this year’s midterm elections. (We considered doing a third chart that combines the partisan composition of both the presidency and Congress, but there weren’t enough data points for every possible permutation to draw any reasonable conclusions.)

The chart above shows that, under comparable economic circumstances, deficits under divided Congresses have generally been slightly lower than deficits under unified Congresses. The chart also shows that deficits under unified Congresses have been roughly identical in level regardless of which party is in control. But there is one key way in which the partisan control of a unified Congress matters: when at least one chamber of Congress was controlled by Democrats, budget deficits have historically had a modest correlation with unemployment. When Republicans were in full control of Congress, however, deficits have had little to no relationship with the unemployment rate.

This finding appears to reinforce our conclusion from the previous blog: under Democratic governance, budget deficits have been consistent with responsible counter-cyclical fiscal policy. Under Republican governance, they have not.

There are many possible rationales for why Democrats appear to have a better budgetary track record than Republicans. Goldwein hypothesized that “Republican Congresses make Democratic presidents their best (fiscal selves) while they enable Republican presidents to be their worst fiscal selves.” David Leonhardt of the New York Times, whose column last the weekend inspired PPI’s first analysis, suggested that although this phenomenon may have some effect, there have also been instances (specifically in the early years of the Clinton administration) in which Democrats pursued responsible fiscal policy of their own volition that cannot be explained by this “external pressure” theory.

Regardless of the reason, there is relatively strong evidence that the federal budget over the past 40 years has been more responsibly managed under Democrats than Republicans – at least in the short term. Riedl noted that our analysis ignores the impact of policy changes implemented under a president (or Congress) that are inexpensive in the short term while costing more in later years. A cursory review of the record suggests to us that Democrats would likely still come out ahead under this metric over the past 40 years, but for now it remains a very real blind spot we hope to address at some point in the future when we have more time to compile and analyze the data.

Another good point Riedl made is that the biggest contributor to long-term budget deficits is the rising cost of social insurance programs that were created by Democratic administrations more than 40 years ago. These programs, the largest of which are Social Security and Medicare, are growing roughly twice as fast as the economy as more and more baby boomers move into retirement and begin collecting benefits. Other categories of federal spending, meanwhile, are projected to shrink relative to the size of the economy.

Although Democrats have generally been the more fiscally responsible party since the Carter administration, they still need to present voters with a credible plan for making their social insurance legacy from earlier years more fiscally sustainable. Doing so would cement their recent superiority on the issue of responsible fiscal stewardship and save young voters – a key component of the Democratic Party’s base – from being buried under a mountain of debt.

Are Democrats Really the Party of Fiscal Responsibility? Yes, But…

Over the weekend, David Leonhardt published an op-ed in the New York Times entitled “The Democrats Are the Party of Fiscal Responsibility.” Leonhardt argues that Democrats get insufficient credit for the fact that federal budget deficits drop when their party holds the White House while deficits rise when Republicans take control.  We believe Leonhardt is correct in his assessment of the partisan fiscal record, and it’s worth exploring why Democrats don’t get more credit for their accomplishments.

The most commonly used metric for evaluating a country’s fiscal situation is the budget deficit as a percent of gross domestic product, because the same budget deficit in dollars is less significant in the context of a larger national economy than it would be in a smaller one. The government is generally considered to be more fiscally responsible when it minimizes the deficit as a percent of GDP.

The exception to this rule is during an economic downturn. When the economy contracts, deficits can rise as a percent of GDP even if they remain at the same level in dollars. Additionally, temporary stimulus (in the form of either tax cuts or spending increases) is an important tool for combatting these economic downturns. Counter-cyclical deficits allow the government to pump money into the economy when it needs it the most, stimulating demand and reducing unemployment. Some programs, such as Unemployment Insurance, act as “automatic stabilizers” because they do this automatically during a recession without additional action by policymakers.

Leonhardt controls for these factors by comparing deficits as a percent of potential GDP (which is largely unaffected by swings in the business cycle) and by subtracting the impact of automatic stabilizers. In his analysis, Leonhardt found that deficits fell under every Democratic president since Jimmy Carter and rose under every elected Republican president since Ronald Reagan.

This measure, however, still penalizes presidents who choose to use additional stimulus beyond automatic stabilizers to bolster a flailing economy under their watch. An alternative way to analyze the data would be to compare deficits relative to unemployment under the presidents of each party. Below is a chart showing the correlation between deficits and unemployment under both Democratic and Republican presidents in every administration since Jimmy Carter:

Under Democratic presidents, the trend is essentially what one would expect to see from good counter-cyclical fiscal policy: When unemployment rises, so too do deficits. When unemployment falls, deficits fall as well (to the point where they actually became surpluses during the prosperous years at the end of the Clinton administration). This trend suggests a responsible stewardship of the federal budget under Democratic presidents.

The picture under Republican presidents, on the other hand, is very different. When a Republican occupies the White House, deficits have historically had little correlation to unemployment. The trend is continued by President Trump, who supported massive deficit-financed policies over the past year despite the fact that unemployment is just over four percent today. As a result, the non-partisan Congressional Budget Office now projects deficits over the remainder of Trump’s term that are significantly higher than those under any Democratic president presiding over an economy with less than seven percent unemployment.

If the fiscal record of Democratic presidents is so obviously superior to that of Republican presidents, why do Democrats not get credit for being the “party of fiscal responsibility”?

The first reason is that deficits reached their highest level in the modern era (9.8 percent of GDP) during the first year of the Obama administration. This unusually large deficit was a direct result of the 2008 financial crisis that President Obama inherited, and after excluding years in which average unemployment exceeded 8 percent, it becomes apparent that deficits under Democratic presidents have been consistently lower than deficits under Republicans facing comparable economic circumstances. Nevertheless, many voters still associate Democrats with the record-high deficits of the early Obama era.

Another reason Democrats don’t get more credit for declining deficits under their presidencies is that presidents simply do not deserve all the credit for deficit reduction that occurs on their watch. Both Presidents Clinton and Obama had to contend with at least one chamber of Congress being controlled by Republicans for six of their eight years in office. Congressional Republicans, despite being incredibly profligate under Republican presidents, have regularly demanded deep spending cuts when a Democrat occupies the oval office – spending cuts which contribute to declining deficits.

But the main reason Democrats don’t get credit for being “the party of fiscal responsibility” is that they often approach the subject with ambivalence. Many Democrats have been reluctant to criticize the GOP’s fiscal record either because they believe Republicans have demonstrated that deficits don’t matter politically or because they fear that admitting the importance of fiscal responsibility now will constrain their ability to deficit-finance progressive priorities in the future. Until Democrats resolve this ambivalence, voters won’t give the party credit for its responsible stewardship.

Donald Trump has handed Democrats a unique opportunity to correct course. With unified control of the federal government, Republicans have blown a massive hole in the federal budget. The nation may never again see an annual budget deficit below $1 trillion after 2020 if current policies remain in place. At a time when deficits are high and trust in government is low, Democrats need to demonstrate they have plan to pay for their policies if they expect voters to support further expansions of government. Now is the time to hold Republicans accountable for their reckless fiscal policy and offer the electorate a compelling alternative.

For more on this topic, please see our second blog that focuses on the fiscal record of each party in Congress.

Kim for Washington Monthly, “The Mirage of ‘Full Employment'”

Low unemployment rates mask soft spots in the job market, especially among rural Americans and minorities.

For the last several months, Republicans have been resting on the laurels of positive job growth and low unemployment—proof, they say, of the Trump economy’s strength. In March, the nation’s official jobless rate stood at 4.1 percent, the lowest it’s been since the peak of the Great Recession and a level that many economists say is at or approaching “full employment.”

Certainly on paper, the labor market looks to be nearly as tight as it was during past expansions, such as during the boom of the late 1990s and early 2000s. In reality, however, the low official unemployment rate masks some serious weaknesses in the economy, including in the parts of the country that are the strongholds of Trump’s support.

Rural job growth, for example, is lackluster in comparison to that of cities. And while college graduates and the highly-skilled are in demand, minorities and lesser-skilled workers are still struggling. The share of people actually participating in the labor market is also significantly lower than in the past, including among “prime-age” adults between the ages of 25 and 54 who are the backbone of the job market. Simply put, fewer Americans are working or even looking for jobs. This means the decline in jobless rates reflects to some extent a shrinking pool of Americans looking for work.

Continue reading at Washington Monthly.

Happy Holidays from PPI

It’s been a surreal political year, but PPI has much to celebrate this holiday season. Throughout 2017, we expanded our productive capacity and the scope of our political and media outreach significantly. For example, PPI organized 150 meetings with prominent elected officials; visited 10 state capitals and 10 foreign capitals, published an influential book and more than 40 original research papers, and hosted nearly 30 private salon dinners on a variety of topical issues.
Best of all, we saw PPI’s research, analysis, and innovative ideas breaking through the political static and changing the way people think about some critical issues, including how to revive U.S. economic dynamism, spread innovation and jobs to people and places left behind by economic growth, and modernize the ways we prepare young people for work and citizenship.
Let me give you some highlights:
  • This fall, David Osborne’s new book, Reinventing America’s Schools, was published on the 25th anniversary of the nation’s first charter school in Minnesota. David, who heads PPI’s Reinventing America’s Schools project, documents the emergence of a new “21st Century” model for organizing and modernizing our public school system around the principles of school autonomy, accountability, choice, and diversity. David is just winding up a remarkable 20-city book tour that drew wide attention from education, political, and civic leaders, as well as the media. Because David is a great storyteller, as well as analyst, it’s a highly readable book that offers a cogent picture of a K-12 school system geared to the demands of the knowledge economy. It makes a great holiday gift!
  • Dr. Michael Mandel’s pioneering research on e-commerce and job creation also upended conventional wisdom and caught the attention of top economic commentators. Dr. Mandel, PPI’s chief economic strategist, found that online commerce has actually created more jobs in retail than it destroys, and that these new jobs (many in fulfillment centers in outlying areas) pay considerably better than traditional ones. His research buttresses the main premise of PPI’s progressive pro-growth agenda: that spreading digital innovation to the physical economy will create new jobs and businesses, raise labor productivity, and reduce inequality.
  • PPI challenged the dubious panacea of “free college” and proposed a progressive alternative – a robust system of post-secondary learning and credentials for the roughly 70 percent of young Americans who don’t get college degrees. PPI Senior Fellow Harry Holzer developed a creative menu of ways to create more “hybrid learning” opportunities combining work-based and classroom instruction. And PPI Senior Fellow Anne Kim highlighted the inequity of current government policies that subsidize college-bound youth (e.g., Pell Grants), but provide no help for people earning credentials certifying skills that employers value.
  • Building on last year’s opening of a PPI office in Brussels, we expanded our overseas work considerably in 2017. In January, I endeavored to explain the outcome of the U.S. election to shell-shocked audiences in London, Brussels, and Berlin. In April, we led our annual Congressional senior staff delegation to Paris, Brussels, and Berlin to engage European policymakers on the French presidential election and other U.S-E.U. issues, including international taxation, competition policy, and trade. PPI also took its message of data-driven innovation and growth to Australia, Brazil, Japan and a number of other countries.
Other 2017 highlights included a strategy retreat in February with two dozen top elected leaders to explore ideas for a new, radically pragmatic agenda for progressives; a Washington conference with our longtime friend Janet Napolitano (now President of the University of California system) on how to update and preserve NAFTA; public forums in Washington on pricing carbon, infrastructure, tax reform, and other pressing issues; creative policy reports on varied subjects; and a robust output of articles, op-eds, blogs, and social media activity.
I’m also happy to report many terrific additions to PPI in 2017. Rob Keast joined to manage our external relations and new policy development; Paul Bledsoe assumed a new role as Strategic Adviser as well as guiding our work on energy and climate policy; and Emily Langhorne joined as Education Policy Analyst. We will also be adding a fiscal project next year.
All this leaves us poised for a high-impact year in 2018. In this midterm-election year, our top priority will be crafting and building support for a new progressive platform — a radically pragmatic alternative to the political tribalism throttling America’s progress. That starts with new and better ideas for solving peoples’ problems that look forward, not backward, and that speak to their hopes and aspirations, not their anger and mistrust.
It’s a tall order, and we cannot succeed without your help and support. Thanks for all you have done over past years, and we look forward to working with you in 2018.
Happy holidays and New Year!

PPI & Republican Main Street: New Workplace Flexibility Bill is a Win-Win for Employers & Working Families

WASHINGTON – Following the introduction of H.R. 4219, the Workflex in the 21st Century Act, Republican Main Street Partnership and the Progressive Policy Institute today released statements in support of the new legislation. Introduced by Rep. Mimi Walters (CA-45), the bill provides American businesses and their employees with greater choice, flexibility and predictability for the schedule and structure of their workplace.

“To balance the demands of work, family, and the curveballs life throws at you, PPI has long supported flexible work arrangements for workers, including paid parental, family, and medical leave. The Workflex in the 21st Century Act grants both part-time and full-time employees the paid leave and workflex benefits they need, like compressed and predictable work scheduling and telework, while providing employers with the flexibility they need to administer these benefits,” said Progressive Policy Institute President Will Marshall.

“For employers looking to attract a talented workforce, the legislation creates a voluntary program of compensable leave based on employment size and the amount of time an employee has spent with the company. Under this voluntary approach, employers would be obliged not only to provide generous leave but also to offer their employees more flexible work arrangements. In return, companies could avoid rigid, one-size-fits-all mandates that make it difficult to create the nimble, responsive workplaces today’s economy demands. This proposal would not relieve any company of the responsibility to offer paid leave; companies that don’t opt-in would continue to be subject to state mandates.

“The collaborative Workflex approach is thus a win-win solution for workers and employers, and as such deserves the support of pro-growth progressives.”

“Since starting the Women2Women Conversations Tour in 2014, I have heard from families across the country who are looking for a sustainable work-life balance that is supported in the workplace,” said Sarah Chamberlain, President and CEO of Republican Main Street Partnership. “As modern life demands more of our time and attention, workplace flexibility is an innovative and common sense solution for families nationwide. Workflex is a responsible approach and a welcome step for employees and employers alike.”

The Workflex in the 21st Century Act would help employees strike a better work-life balance. Studies have shown that employees want a workplace that supports both their personal and professional responsibilities. Employers who choose to adopt a workflex plan would be required to provide paid leave to all employees and offer all employees the option to participate in at least one of six flexible scheduling options, such as telework or predictable scheduling. Importantly, paid leave can be used as employees see fit: there are no restrictions. For more information on this legislation, please click here.

###

Press Release: New PPI Report Offers Pragmatic Alternative to “Free College” Proposal

Free credentials would help millions of Americans without four-year degrees reach the middle-class debt free & close labor force “skills gap”

WASHINGTON —The Progressive Policy Institute (PPI) today released a new policy report by senior fellow Anne Kim, “Forget ‘free college.’ How about ‘free credentials?,'” proposing greater federal support of high-quality occupational credentialing opportunities as an alternative to a “free” four-year degree. The report finds that federal support of such programs—including the extension of federal Pell grants—would help close the “skills gap” and provide an equally viable and debt-free path to middle-class mobility and economic security.

“The single-minded focus on college diminishes other, equally viable paths to middle-class security – such as in health care, information technology, advanced manufacturing, and other skilled professions – that require specialized occupational ‘credentials’ but no four-year degree,” writes Kim.

“If progressives truly want to expand opportunity, they should reverse the lopsided bias toward college, both in politics and in policy, rather than reinforcing it. In particular, federal and state policymakers should embrace the role that high-quality, short-term credentialing programs can play in boosting workers’ skills and wages.”

Kim argues that current higher education policy is heavily tilted toward a monolithic view of postsecondary education – as a single block of time in the life of a young adult between the ages of 18 and 22 with a four-year degree as the optimal outcome. It’s a framework that fails to acknowledge the needs of both students and employers in today’s rapidly changing economy. And it sends the wrong message to the millions of Americans who opt out of college – not because they can’t afford it but don’t want it or need it to achieve their aspirations. As pollster Pete Brodnitz of Expedition Strategies puts it, insisting on college as the ideal path is “essentially telling people they have the wrong dream.” “A lot of people want jobs that involve trades or skills,” says Brodnitz, “not a liberal arts education.”

The report finds that many of the jobs that require a credential, but no college degree, pay salaries that comfortably put workers into the middle class. Such “middle-skill” jobs can pay as much as $90,420. Importantly, Kim notes, quality credentialing programs can also be a valuable postsecondary alternative for older and nontraditional students for whom a commitment to full-time or part-time coursework in a traditional college setting may be unrealistic, impractical, or unnecessary. And because they typically take weeks or months to earn, not years, credentials can help workers who’ve been displaced rapidly redeploy themselves into new careers with demonstrated employer demand.

###

Expansion of the Joint Employer Doctrine Fails to Strike the Right Balance

Policymakers across the United States are struggling to figure out how to adapt to swift changes in the American workforce. So-called “alternative work arrangements,” for example, are growing: in 2015, 15.8 percent of workers were independent contractors, temporary workers, contracted workers, or “gig” workers—a 50 percent increase in just a decade. Yet some efforts at adaptation—such as expansion of the “joint employer” doctrine—may do more harm than good. PPI is committed to helping find solutions that balance worker protection with business productivity and investment and the expansion of the joint employer doctrine fails to strike that balance. We must figure out a better way forward that boosts economic dynamism without sacrificing worker interests.

At the end of July, the Save Local Business Act was introduced into the House of Representatives. The bill, with three Democratic cosponsors among over three dozen Republicans, aims to narrow the expanded definition of “joint employer” promulgated by the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB) in 2015. This elicited immediate praise from business groups—particularly those associated with franchises—and opposition from unions and other groups advocating for worker rights.

The joint employer doctrine is used by the NLRB and courts in determining legal responsibility for issues such as overtime pay when more than one employer is involved. If a bank, for example, contracts with a company to provide janitors to clean the bank facilities, the janitors are employees of the contract firm, not the bank. Yet, if the bank has some level of control over of the janitors’ wages and hours, it could be deemed a “joint employer” and would be responsible for appropriate legal compliance.

Not incidentally, the joint employer doctrine is central in shaping the ability of employees to engage in collective bargaining. Contract workers, temporary workers, and franchise employees—all of whom are affected by the joint employer doctrine—are difficult to unionize. Employees of franchise locations—fast-food restaurants, for example—are technically employees of the franchisee (the local operator), not the franchisor (the national brand). The entire purpose of the franchising model is to allow the franchisor to focus on brand and system, and leave the franchisee to focus on operations and local context, including employment.

Under the expanded joint employer doctrine of the NLRB, however, it is possible that both the franchisee and the franchisor could be considered employers of the workers at each individual franchise location. This “could fundamentally change business in the United States by destroying the franchise model.”

Until the 1980s, the NLRB threshold for a joint employer finding was “direct or indirect control” over working conditions. This was a fairly broad doctrine and, in certain circumstances, could be used to find that employees were subject to “control” by more than one employer. Nonetheless, the NLRB joint employer standard remained more modest than definitions used in Title VII of the Civil Rights Act and the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA).

Beginning in the 1980s, the NLRB gradually narrowed the definition to “direct and immediate” control over employment issues. The change from “indirect” to “immediate” had large implications in where the joint-employer line was drawn. If the bank “shares or codetermines” the conditions of employment of the contracted janitors, and “meaningfully affects” their hiring, firing, supervision, etc., the company could be a joint employer. Now, the NLRB says, no longer is “direct and immediate control” required—even the possession of authority to direct third-party employees is sufficient, regardless of whether the authority is exercised.

These subtleties in language and reliance on factual findings are classic examples of legalese, but cases involving worker rights and business interests frequently turn on choice of words and how those words are put into practice.

Business groups do not welcome a broader definition. Especially as it pertains to franchise arrangements, the more expansive standard could open up franchisors to greater liability and more attempts at collective bargaining. Already, we have seen arguments to apply the extended joint employer doctrine to other areas, such as student athletes. A challenge to the NLRB’s expansive interpretation is currently pending in front of the D.C. Circuit, and it is expected that the NLRB under President Trump will work to narrow the standard. In the Republican-controlled Congress, the Save Local Business Act could find easy passage and, at the state level, legislatures are being lobbied to pass laws saying that franchisors cannot be considered joint employers.

One problem is the likely response from franchisors to the expanded NLRB standard—in particular, we may see reduced business dynamism. Franchising is an engine of entrepreneurship in the United States, with independent operators who, despite the assistance of national brands, assume plenty of financial risk themselves. At the same time, we have seen the rise of large franchising operations that own hundreds of franchises across the country. Not surprisingly, large franchising operations are better able to comply with employment laws than small, single-operator franchisees. Faced with the new incentive structure of the expanded joint employer doctrine, franchisors will have a clear preference against smaller franchisees in favor of the larger organizations. This will make it much harder for new entrepreneurs to enter business through franchising, further raising barriers of entry for business creation.

The NLRB and other public agencies have the unenviable task of modifying law and policy to keep up with shifting employment arrangements, in an environment of stagnant wages for many workers, geographic concentration of economic rewards, and concerns about entire occupational categories being lost to automation. As mentioned, “alternative work” is growing. The Government Accountability Office (GAO) estimates that the “contingent workforce,” depending on the definitions used, could be anywhere from five to 40 percent of the total labor force. More people are receiving income from multiple sources, which includes new online and on-demand platforms. These changes have prompted calls for new legal classifications, such as the “independent worker” category proposed by the Hamilton Project two years ago.

Confronted with these challenges, expanding the joint employer doctrine is perhaps an understandable attempt to try to help workers cope. The fastest-growing type of alternative work arrangements is “workers provided by contract firms,” precisely those at the core of the joint employer doctrine. Yet we also need to help policymakers and businesses think creatively about other ways to manage and adapt to these challenges, as they will only increase in significance. In the face of a “fissured workplace,” how can policymakers help workers and businesses adapt and succeed together?

In managing these changes, we must ensure adequate worker protection and representation while also supporting (or at least not hindering) businesses to pursue innovation and productivity. Policymaking should be guided by certain principles, among which might be the following.

  • Clarity and certainty. Any standard leaves room for interpretation (and litigation), but workers and firms need to have clear ideas about where they stand regarding rights and responsibilities.
  • Get the incentives right. Policies should minimize the amount of “gaming” that might go on by firms in trying to avoid legal compliance. This doesn’t mean the presumption should be that all firms will act badly—policymakers need to pay attention to the incentives they establish.
  •  New ways for workers to organize and improve. Despite the NLRB’s presumption, traditional unions may not be the best adaptive form of organizing in the modern workplace, and new Internet platforms have arisen to help fill the gap. Policy should facilitate these, but also focus on how new organizing tools can support learning and skill upgrading among workers, not just collective bargaining.
  • Informational equity and transparency. As the Roosevelt Institute has coherently outlined, employees in more sectors are subject to “opaque algorithms” that determine wages, scheduling, evaluation, and so on. Giving workers more transparency and control over this information will reduce asymmetry and empower workers to better manage their careers.

Most of the American labor force is still characterized by traditional employment, but new forms of work are growing rapidly, especially in sectors where low-wage and high-turnover work predominates. Addressing this challenge is a major priority, and we need to find ways that policy can jointly advance the interests of workers and firms.

How Ecommerce Creates Jobs and Reduces Income Inequality

The last retail revolution, the rise of the big box store, was not a good thing for the typical sales clerk or cashier.

“Warehouse clubs” and “supercenters” started popping up everywhere in the late 1980s. Retail productivity as measured by the government doubled from 1987 to 2007, as this new retail format was more efficient than traditional department stores and mom-and-pop operations, many of which were pushed out of business. Nevertheless, average real wages for
retail workers actually fell from 1987 to 2007, and the pay gap between retail workers and the rest of the workforce widened.

Now comes the ecommerce revolution. Given the bad experience of workers with the last retail revolution, it’s only natural to worry that this one will have an equally bad effect. As of the new first quarter of 2017, ecommerce has less than 9% of retail sales. What will happen to brick-and-mortar retail workers as 10% or 20%of sales move onto the Internet? Are we facing
a retail “apocalypse” that will destroy jobs that employ 15% of the American work.



			

Yarrow for SF Chronicle: “Fathers’ unemployment taking huge toll on children”

“After I got divorced in 1999, I had custody of my kids, but I went out of my way to drop them at their mother’s house over the weekends,” said a 47-year-old African American man in Baltimore. He lost his job during the 2008 recession and was out of work for two years. After finding and losing another job, he lost his house, and his teenage daughters moved in with their mother. “Things should have been done differently,” he said. “I felt like they didn’t listen to me and based my value on my income.”

The decline of men at work has primarily been seen as a labor-market or broader economic issue. Yet it is a child-welfare issue of concern to us all. For the sake of their children, millions of working-age men need to work.

Many fathers and mothers are out of work for some period while their children are growing up, yet the effects on kids of fathers not working has received relatively little attention. This is a significant and growing problem, as about 13 million 25- to 64-year-old men are not working, and several million more are in part-time jobs not by choice, according to U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics economist Steve Hipple. This number excludes about 1.1 million incarcerated fathers.

Continue Reading at San Francisco Chronicle. 

L.A. Times: Don’t stress over robots; a bright new economy is being born

Good news: The robots may not destroy us after all.

A few weeks ago, I wrote a column that outlined the worries of big thinkers such as Stephen Hawking and Andrew Yang who are predicting a wave of job destruction caused by automation, robots and artificial intelligence.

Michael Mandel begs to differ. Mandel is chief economic strategist at the Progressive Policy Institute. He and Bret Swanson, president of Entropy Economics LLC, just completed a study for the Tech CEO Council that foresees a rather bright economic future brought about by technological innovation.

I recently interviewed Mandel and he made a compelling argument that the application of technology to the physical economy will, in time, produce more jobs, higher wages, greater productivity and all kinds of as-yet-unimagined business activity. The two doomsday narratives that are currently circulating — that robots will steal jobs and that productivity will lag more or less permanently — are as wrong as the 19th century fears that electrification would put people out of work, Mandel said.

Continue reading at L.A. Times.